What’s jawboning?
Central banks don’t have to move the cash rate to get their way. Another part of monetary policy is called “jawboning”. This involves a bank making public commentary to influence markets that may be betting on a rate change one way or the other (which in turn can influence things such as the value of the currency).
Through most of 2018,Reserve Bank governor Philip Lowe would say interest rates were more likely to go up than down when asked about the direction of monetary policy. This was effectively a warning to financial markets,businesses and people wanting to buy a home to expect a lift in borrowing costs.
Interest rate movements and jawboning form the key elements of “conventional monetary policy”. The world has seen the other side of that coin over the past 12 months – so-called unconventional monetary policy. This can include taking official interest rates below zero (as a number of countries across the globe have done) or engaging in what is known as quantitative easing. This involves a central bank printing money to buy assets - usually government debt - in a bid to reduce interest rates on this type of debt. The money printed for the asset then flows into the economy where it,hopefully,increases overall economic activity.
The aim is to make money so cheap,for an extended period of time,that businesses and consumers start investing and spending so that economic activity starts to increase.
Why does the bank have a 2 to 3 per cent inflation target?
The Reserve Bank’s inflation target is only a relatively recent phenomenon. Put in place by then governor Bernie Fraser in the early 1990s,it was formally codified by treasurer Peter Costello soon after he took office in 1996.
The Reserve Bank of New Zealand was the first central bank to set an inflation target in the late 1980s. Other countries quickly followed the Kiwi lead and today about 67 central banks have a formal inflation target.
Loading
Before this,central banking went through two major phases. Between 1945 and 1971,the Australian dollar was “pegged” to its US counterpart. Interest rates and the currency (which was controlled by the federal government) were changed to ensure the Australian dollar moved in line with the US dollar.
But the system broke down in the early 1970s. From 1976,the bank decided to target the money supply. This was based on the theory that inflation was linked to the growth of the money supply.
Most other central banks took this approach but by the early 1980s,largely due to the deregulation of the financial system (caps on mortgage and interest rates were ended,foreign banks were allowed into Australia in 1985),and the system also effectively collapsed.
This left all central banks looking for a particular target against which to measure their efforts to set monetary policy.
Internal research by the RBA through the later part of the 1980s backed what other central banks were discovering – an inflation target was key to interest rate setting.

During World War I,the Commonwealth Bank raised money for the war effort by selling war bonds. It often used emotive posters such as these to entice Australians to help fund the defence effort.Credit:RBA
How did Australia’s Reserve Bank evolve?
When the Commonwealth started on January 1,1901,currency was produced by private banks and by the Queensland government. There was no central bank.
The Labor government of Andrew Fisher passed laws giving it control of our currency in 1910,outlawing state governments from printing notes and taxing private banks that did so. The next year,the government created its own trading and savings bank – the Commonwealth Bank. Within three years,it was taking up one of the key roles of a central bank by securing loans from overseas to help pay for Australia’s involvement in World War I.The first note – for 10 shillings – was printed in early 1913 on a press in Flinders Street,Melbourne.
In 1920,the responsibility for bank notes was shifted from Treasury to an independent Australian Notes Board,a separate department of the Commonwealth Bank and chaired by the bank’s governor. Four years later,treasurer Earle Page amended the bank’s legislation with the intention of turning it into a proper central bank. There was only one problem – Page did not really explain to the Commonwealth Bank what he wanted.

The opening day of the Commonwealth Bank of Australia in Martin Place,Sydney,on August 22,1916. The bank was opened by then prime minister Billy Hughes.Credit:RBA
According to political economist Lyndhurst Giblin,when the bank’s board of directors were appointed by Page in 1924,they were given a blank sheet of paper to map out Australian monetary policy. “Both the aims and the methods of central banking were left undefined and the whole problem was put upon the new bank board,referred to hopefully as ‘the experts’,” he wrote in a book on the early history of the bank.
The problem was that the board of directors (including Sir Samuel Hordern,president of the NSW Royal Agricultural Society and after whom Sydney’s well-known Hordern Pavilion is named) believed they were experts. The bank itself was made up mostly of people versed in day-to-day banking. They had little knowledge of central banking.
Giblin notes this situation went on for some time. “For some years the Board seemed to be blissfully unconscious of the need of help and almost to have resented the idea of any technical assistance as beneath its dignity,” he wrote.
So confused was the bank that it asked the governor of the Bank of England to visit Australia. He turned down the chance,but sent a senior official out in 1927.
The election of the Scullin government,just days before the Black Friday collapse of Wall Street in October 1929 that precipitated the Great Depression,resulted in a renewed effort to set up Australia’s central bank.
New treasurer Ted Theodore proposed the day-to-day trading activities of the Commonwealth Bank be hived off into a new entity,leaving a standalone central reserve bank to focus on monetary policy and the circulation of notes.
He also proposed the bank board have nine members:the governor,no more than two deputy governors,the Treasury secretary and five outside individuals who would be,or had been,actively engaged in agriculture,commerce,finance,industry and labour.
The entire plan went down in the Senate where the then conservative opposition feared this new,broader board would extend the powers of the central bank.
The bank itself was uncomfortable with the Scullin government’s planned response to the Great Depression with Theodore proposing a series of public works that the Commonwealth Bank would have to fund.
A royal commission into the banking system in 1937 argued the bank’s actions,including pushing up the value of Australia’s currency,had worsened the depression’s impact.
It would take another 30 years before the Reserve Bank was separated from its private day-to-day banking activities. But the notion of a board made up of senior executives and people from the broader economy overseeing the bank had been planted and remains today.
The Curtin and then Chifley governments were the first to openly confirm the Commonwealth Bank was the nation’s central bank as part of sweeping changes they introduced in 1945.
Through the 1950s,the Menzies government took a series of steps that ultimately led to the Commonwealth losing its central banking roles to a brand new institution – the Reserve Bank of Australia that started operations on January 14,1960.
By 1965,it had established its current headquarters in Martin Place,Sydney.

Herbert “Nugget” Coombs,pictured here in 1951,headed the Commonwealth Bank when it was the nation’s central bank between 1949 and 1960 and then became the RBA’s first governor,serving until 1968. He is the nation’s longest-serving central bank governor.Credit:Sun News
Is the bank under the government’s control?
While the RBA was created by government,it is certainly not under its thumb. The Treasurer of the day appoints the bank governor for a seven-year term. The bank and Treasury have a list of possible board members but,ultimately,the choice sits with the treasurer.
But after that the government has almost no control over the bank and its decisions. Australian treasurers have taken to rarely making direct comment on the RBA’s actions,especially around the setting of interest rates.
There is scrutiny of the bank. Twice a year,the governor and senior staff face the House of Representatives’ Economics Committee for three hours of questioning. But in most cases,this turns more into a political point-scoring effort by the assembled MPs rather than a deep inquisition of monetary policy settings.
Senior staff take questions from the public after the many speeches they present through the year. But it was only in 2020 that the governor faced a press conference - albeit two virtual ones - to answer questions about major policy changes.
Through the 1970s and 1980s,the importance of monetary policy being set independently of politicians became clear to economists,academics and,finally,the political class. Central banks have since used this independence to make tough calls that have caused politicians plenty of problems.
Just days out from the 2007 federal election,the Reserve Bank used its traditional Melbourne Cup Day meeting to lift official interest rates by a quarter percentage point to 6.75 per cent.
It was the first time a bank had increased rates during an election campaign,one in which the Howard government was arguing interest rates would go up under Kevin Rudd’s Labor Party. Then treasurer Peter Costello,in his autobiography,noted that prior to him taking the job,the treasurer of the day would announce an interest rate change.
“And no treasurer would announce a rate rise during a campaign,” he wrote. “The fact that the RBA made its announcement in the feverish last weeks of an election campaign demonstrated,once and for all,its independence.”

Reserve bank Governor Philip Lowe,ahead of his address to the National Press Club in Canberra in February.Credit:Dominic Lorrimer
What can’t central banks control?
Central bankers can get blamed for all sorts of things. Current governor Philip Lowe has noted on many occasions the letters of complaint he receives from people who have savings,upset at another cut in deposit rates.
Interest rate settings have a substantial impact on house prices,prompting concerns it has added to the nation’s housing affordability crisis.
And then there are bananas.
In 2006,Cyclone Larry wiped out large parts of the nation’s banana crop. This contributed towards an uptick in inflation with the Reserve Bank increasing official interest rates on three separate occasions that year.
Then governor Ian Macfarlane,facing the House Economics Committee in August of that year,rejected complaints from members of the government and the public that monetary policy was being held hostage by high-priced bananas.
“We actually know what the price of bananas are,” he said,becoming the only RBA governor to ever comment directly on banana prices.